Growth vs. Productivity

0
195

It’s a chicken and egg problem

 

 

Put simplistically, with the underlying advantage of cheap labor getting eroded,

naturally competitiveness took a hit and the result is what we see today:

declining exports and heavy closures in domestic manufacturing.

 

 

 

Pakistani businesses are doing a terrible job at making their workers more productive. Productivity growth has been the weakest since the early 1980s. Recorded at only about 0.8 percent a year over the last decade, when compared with 2.3 percent (on average) for a period from 1947 to 2007. This most argue is perhaps also the root cause of slow growth in both: gross domestic product and workers’ pay. At least, this is the standard way of thinking about productivity and its relationship to the economy. In a mainstream view, productivity is a kind of magic force that helps explain rising output.

 

New laborsaving inventions come along or new management practices are taken up that miraculously allows companies to produce more output with fewer hours of work. However, in this viewpoint, one can’t really predict when and how such innovations will arrive. For example, in the USA, when Henry Ford started using a moving assembly line or when Sam Watson perfected the just-in-time supply chain or when easy-to-use word processors suddenly became affordable resulting in fewer business people needing secretaries, Voila, the productive capacity of the nation rose, along with incomes and living standards.

 

Closer to home, in Pakistan, this was last seen in the 80s when domestic textile operations introduced revolutionary man to machine ratios never seen before in the history of the textile industry, and as a result Pakistan jumped to being the third largest textile grey goods producer from being a lowly 21st before that.

 

But what if this is the wrong way of thinking? What if productivity growth is not so much an external force that proceeds in random fits and starts, but is deeply intertwined with the overall state of the economy and the labor market? It is chicken or egg problem: Does low productivity cause slow growth or does slow growth cause low productivity? The second possibility is a provocative argument of a paper recently published by the Roosevelt Institute, a liberal think tank.

 

The paper argues that United States (US) economy is not actually closing in on its full economic potential and has plenty of room for continued growth – so long as the Federal Reserve does not put the brakes on the expansion prematurely. J.W. Mason, the author of the report, argues that soft productivity growth reflects not some unlucky dearth of new innovations, but rather is a consequence of depressed demand for goods and services and a slack labor market that has in-turn depressed wages.

 

According to Mason, this can only be addressed by spurring investment in the domestic manufacturing markets and not by artificially increasing minimum wage or benefits. He goes on to argue that once investment is robust and once when may be the labor markets were tighter and wages were rising faster, it would induce companies to invest more heavily, albeit this time in new-labor-saving innovations. What is particularly interesting is that this diagnosis – though decidedly not the policy prescriptions yet in the developed economies – has some overlap with the arguments of influential conservative economists. Again, a recent paper published by the Hoover Institution (HI) and American Enterprise Institute (AEI) argued that the production drought in the US was caused by insufficient investment in capital equipment, software, and was poised to rebound in the shape that we see today.

 

It argues, wages raised artificially without any real correlation to market forces – that is supply and demand of labor – will not only be counterproductive but in reality, will hinder investment as companies will go out of business to foreign competitors before being able to meet productivity related investments.

 

So, what in essence this paper by HI and AEI (3 out of 4 authors of this paper are by the way considered as potential future nominees to lead the Federal Reserve) is saying is that in principle, “Wages should not be fixed arbitrarily by governments and that only Investment and not anything else should be the most powerful force in efforts by companies for driving up their productivity.

 

And such investments in manufacturing, ironically has been the weakest in US corporations over the last decade. Companies, according to the authors, are spending their capital budgets not on things that might cause a leap in their workers’ productivity, but on projects to replace old machinery and software and play catch up in order to get to marginal efficiency gains.

 

In the context of minimum wage debate, pretty much everyone (USA, European Union economies, Brazil South Africa and now even India through its latest labor reforms) in the developed economies is unanimous that the argument about ‘capital substitution’ in response to the increase in minimum wage does not hold true. Despite many studies on this relationship in recent years – interestingly also one including from Fudon University, China – none finds any hard evidence that capital substitution would indeed take place as an aftermath of a minimum-wage increase.

 

Now ditto this to the situation in Pakistan and what one sees is that we are also suffering from the very malaise on productivity that the HI & AEI paper has been argued upon. Despite excessive labor supply in the market, respective governments have been artificially jacking up minimum wage rates in routine ever year and that too to levels, which carry little business justification.

 

Put simplistically, with the underlying advantage of cheap labor getting eroded, naturally competitiveness took a hit and the result is what we see today: declining exports and heavy closures in domestic manufacturing. To make matters worse ‘Darnomics’ over the last 4 years played further havoc. By unnecessarily burdening the rather tiny base of taxpayers it drained profitability from legitimate manufacturing operations, in-turn restraining the real potential for in-house investment that could have eventually led to a meaningful growth in productivity.

 

History tells us that the strongest productivity growth in Pakistan came in the 60s and then the 80s. In both periods advertently or in-advertently the governments of the day focused on investment to carry the day for them economically; and it worked. Every time, we have resorted to cheap but (ironically) popular political slogans instead of sound economic rationale to make policy decisions, both productivity and (as a result) the country have suffered!